Categories: Stories

Africa-Why we need to study economies, not economics

In the 1990s and 2000s, economists looking at Africa were typically preoccupied with the continent’s apparent “chronic failure of growth”. The economic literature took it as a given that there was a Bottom Africa’s chronic failure only holds true if you ignore the 1950s, 1960s, 1970s and then the 1990s and 2000s.

However, for those economists attempting to tease out a clean causal effect for the lack of growth, it soon became clear causality runs both ways – for example, budget deficits can cause a lack of growth, but lack of growth can also cause budget deficits. Furthermore, the number of potential explanatory variables discovered mushroomed. A survey found that up to 2005, 145 variables had been found to be significantly correlated with growth.

What I call the ‘second generation’ of economic growth literature thus took a different tack. It skipped explaining growth in this way and instead put its energies into finding the one root cause that had trapped African economies through history. While previously economists had looked for correlations between slow growth and ongoing growth-inhibiting factors, now they searched for an overarching historical variable that could account for both. The problem of reverse causality was side-stepped, and the search for the answer moved to libraries, archives and yearbooks.

This second generation of literature has now generated a list of variables to rival the first. For instance, low economic growth today has been found to be correlated with colonisation, slave exports, distance to the equator, the plough, high malaria prevalence and many others things. Economists understand that history matters.

However, beyond the correlation between a historical dataset and GDP per capita in the present day, everything else – i.e. the actual history – is still missing. Branko Milanovic has called this particular combination of simplistic history and advanced statistical models “Wikipedia with regressions”. I have come to think this is an insult to Wikipedia.

One of the big findings of this new historical approach is that economists will tell you institutions matter. This much is true. But again, without looking at history and the reality of how institutions and economies really interact, a lot is misunderstood. In what Lant Pritchett calls the “why aren’t you more like Denmark” policy implication, economists in this school of thought look simplistically at the history and suppose that good institutions led to Denmark’s wealth while bad institutions led to, say, Chad’s relative poverty.

But the truth, as economic historians will know, is that institutions evolve in complex ways and that economic history is full of examples of growth coinciding with imperfect institutions – take for example the Gold Coast becoming a leading producer of cocoa in the early 19th century or China’s growth since the 1970s. Good institutions can be a result of economic development, not just their cause.

One may celebrate the fact that economists are more fully recognising that institutions and history matter. But this realisation could end up leading us down the wrong path if we don’t have a meaningful definition of what it means for an institution to be ‘good’. One thing we know for sure is that economic development requires different kinds of institutions at different moments and in different places. And if this is true, then measuring institutions according to a single normative global scale from 1 to 10 doesn’t make sense.

If the current trend in economic literature on Africa is correct in saying that history and institutions matter, the types of regressions researchers are relying on should be abandoned in favour of deep contextual studies of these histories and institutions. Instead of studying economics, we need to be studying economies.

At the moment, the literature has found a relationship between lack of development and having the ‘wrong history’ or ‘bad institutions’. But we need to turn this around and study how African economies work, rather than focusing solely on explaining why they don’t. History and politics matter. But that should be our starting point, not our conclusion.

By Morten Jerven- Jerven is the author of Africa: Why Economists Get it Wrong

Thius article was reproduced from African Arguments

(44 VIEWS)

This post was last modified on %s = human-readable time difference 5:50 pm

Charles Rukuni

The Insider is a political and business bulletin about Zimbabwe, edited by Charles Rukuni. Founded in 1990, it was a printed 12-page subscription only newsletter until 2003 when Zimbabwe's hyper-inflation made it impossible to continue printing.

Recent Posts

Can the ZiG sustain its rally against the US dollar?

Zimbabwe’s battered currency, the Zimbabwe Gold, which was under attack until the central bank devalued…

November 10, 2024

Will Mnangagwa go against the trend in the region?

Plans by the ruling Zimbabwe African National Union-Patriotic Front to push President Emmerson Mnangagwa to…

October 22, 2024

The Zimbabwe government and not saboteurs sabotaging ZiG

The Zimbabwe government’s insatiable demand for money to satisfy its own needs, which has exceeded…

October 20, 2024

The Zimbabwe Gold will regain its value if the government does this…

Economist Eddie Cross says the Zimbabwe Gold (ZiG) will regain its value if the government…

October 16, 2024

Is Harare the least democratic province in Zimbabwe?

Zimbabwe’s capital, Harare, which is a metropolitan province, is the least democratic province in the…

October 11, 2024

Zimbabweans against extension of presidential term in office

Nearly 80% of Zimbabweans are against the extension of the president’s term in office, according…

October 11, 2024